Clearing the air
How carbon pricing helps Canada fight climate change
Canadians increasingly agree that climate change requires action. Evidence continues to mount that melting ice packs and extreme weather events pose serious risks to Canadians and their economy. Other climate impacts, such as sea level rise and warmer temperatures, are of particular concern to Canada’s coastal and Arctic communities. The risks are even worse for other, more vulnerable countries.
Despite its relatively small population, Canada has a role to play in the global efforts to reduce greenhouse gas (GHG) emissions to avoid the worst of these risks. Canadians do not want to "free ride" on the actions of others. They want to do their part and contribute to these efforts.
Canadians are also moving closer to agreement on how we should tackle these challenges. Several large provinces have already introduced well-designed carbon-pricing policies. And the federal government is now committed to filling in the remaining policy gaps—by requiring every Canadian province and territory to put a price on carbon by the end of 2018.
That growing consensus around carbon pricing, however, is not yet universal. Various economists and policy experts have made the case for carbon pricing as the best way to reduce GHG emissions while maintaining a strong economy. Yet recently, others have questioned the extent to which carbon pricing will affect GHG emissions. And elections are on the horizon, both nationally and in several provinces, in which carbon pricing could be a source of debate and even a key issue.
Such policy debates are healthy and necessary. Historically, significant shifts in the consensus around policy emerged only after vigorous public discussion. While free trade and balanced budgets might now be broadly accepted, they were once controversial ideas.
But debates will support good policy decisions only if they are based on facts and evidence. And there is strong evidence, grounded in solid economics and policy experience, that carbon pricing works.
Part of the problem is communication. Governments and policy analysts (including here at the Ecofiscal Commission) haven’t always done a good enough job explaining carbon pricing to Canadians. This really matters because carbon pricing affects us all. How we design these policies will influence how we live and how we do business. We all want better understanding.
In short, we need a more informed conversation about carbon pricing. So let’s have that conversation. Let’s clear the air.
The many details of carbon pricing are important for governments to consider when they design good policy. The Ecofiscal Commission has undertaken extensive economic research exploring these details, some of it fairly technical. We’ve explored how to design policy for fairness, and how to design it to ensure Canadian businesses remain competitive. We’ve considered the best ways for governments to recycle revenues generated from carbon pricing. And we’ve looked at the other climate policies that work best with carbon pricing.
Done right, carbon pricing changes household and business behaviour, reduces GHG emissions, and drives the development and adoption of the technologies that will play a key role in a low-carbon economy.
The evidence is clear: carbon pricing shifts us away from "business as usual," changing our emissions trajectory. And higher carbon prices drive deeper emissions reduction.
In addition (and this point is also often overlooked), carbon pricing will achieve these outcomes at a lower economic cost than other policies.
Together, this means carbon pricing can support both a clean economy and a prosperous one. It achieves these goals by changing incentives and unleashing market forces. It lets businesses and individuals identify the best ways to reduce their GHG emissions and at the times and places that are right for them. And it doesn’t require governments to identify specific ways to reduce GHG emissions.
This essay unpacks the overall story. What does “working” mean for carbon pricing? Where has carbon pricing worked? Why does carbon pricing work? When does carbon pricing work? Who supports carbon pricing? How do policies put a price on carbon? We provide clear answers to these questions in simple, (mostly) jargon-free language.
WATCH: Carbon pricing is the solution to climate change that makes sense for both the environment and the economy.
What does "working" mean for carbon pricing?
We focus on two key outcomes that should drive Canada’s climate policy.
First, we should be aiming to reduce our annual greenhouse gas (GHG) emissions. Not just this year but every year going forward. Moving Canada toward deep emissions reductions over time contributes to global efforts to avoid some of the costliest and most uncertain impacts of climate change.
Note that GHGs aren’t just about carbon dioxide. They also include methane, nitrous oxide, and many other gases that collect in Earth’s atmosphere and act like the walls of a greenhouse to lock in heat, raising average global temperatures. Policies that “put a price on carbon” are really designed to put a price on all the major GHGs, wherever feasible.
Second, we should be striving to sustain a strong economy—with the good jobs and incomes that come with it. We can choose to reduce our GHG emissions by having a weak economy, with little production and income, but this is a very costly way to clean up the environment. Far better alternatives are available. Our objective should be to reduce GHG emissions significantly but do so at the lowest possible economic cost.
Can carbon pricing achieve these dual objectives? Yes. We’ll show how throughout this essay.
WATCH: Carbon pricing gives people and businesses flexibility in reducing their emissions.
Where has carbon pricing worked?
Carbon pricing has a track record of success. There are two basic approaches to carbon pricing: carbon taxes and cap-and-trade. It’s also possible to combine them. We’ll get to the details of how they work later. The bottom line is that they all put a price on GHG emissions, which creates an incentive to produce fewer of them.
Here, we’ll explore outcomes in three different jurisdictions that have implemented different types of carbon pricing. None of these policies are perfect, but they all illustrate that carbon pricing works.
Isolating the impact of carbon pricing is critical. Changes in emissions that happen to coincide with new policy aren’t necessarily the result of that policy. In statistics jargon: correlation isn’t the same as causation.
Below, we focus on three case studies that explicitly isolate the impacts of carbon pricing. Using statistical or modelling analysis, these studies aim to answer the question: how would emissions or economic growth be different if carbon pricing policies hadn’t been put into place?
Case Study #1: British Columbia, Canada
British Columbia’s carbon tax started in 2008 at $10 per tonne of carbon emissions, rose by $5 a year, and then paused at $30 in 2012. The tax applied to the burning of fossil fuels, or about 70% of the province’s GHG emissions.
Initially, all revenues were used to finance income-tax cuts and selected tax credits — the carbon tax was “revenue neutral” for the government.
Starting in April 2018, BC’s carbon tax will start rising again by $5 per tonne every year until it hits $50 in 2021. The BC government will use the new revenues to finance initiatives such as public transit and home retrofits to drive further emissions reductions. It will therefore no longer be revenue neutral.
As a result of the carbon tax, annual emissions in BC are 5% to 15% lower than they would otherwise have been. This estimate draws from several analyses (see References for details) each of which isolates the impacts of the carbon tax from other factors.
Those reductions in GHG emissions were the result of various shifts, including:
- The fuel efficiency of BC’s entire vehicle fleet improved by 4% more than it would have without the tax. In other words, people invested in vehicles that would reduce their emissions and thereby allow them to pay less carbon tax by purchasing less gasoline.
- People also changed their gasoline consumption. Per-capita demand for gasoline would be between 7%-17% higher without the carbon tax by 2011. The carbon tax changed the way people drive.
- The carbon tax also affected natural gas use. One analysis suggests that tax reduced residential natural gas demand by 15% and commercial natural gas demand by 65%.
WATCH: Carbon pricing is changing behaviour in British Columbia and California.
Case Study #2: California, United States of America
California introduced a cap-and-trade system in 2012. Under the program, the state sets a cap on how many GHGs its largest industrial emitters can produce and gives them permits, or “allocations,” that allow them to produce GHG emissions.
The minimum price for emissions permits started at $10 per tonne (around $13 Canadian) and will increase at a rate of 5% per year until 2020. Over time, the emissions cap, and therefore the number of permits, will decline, so permit prices will likely increase. The carbon price (permit price) is currently just over $15 per tonne (around $19 Canadian).
The cap initially applied only to electricity producers and manufacturers. In 2015, the cap-and-trade system expanded to include fuels like gasoline and diesel and now applies to 85% of California’s GHG emissions.
The cap falls every year, as required by legislation. From 2015 to 2020, the cap fell just fast enough to allow California to meet its target of reducing GHG emissions to 1990 levels by 2020.
In 2014, California linked its cap-and-trade program with Quebec’s, so companies in the two jurisdictions can trade permits with each other. In 2018, Ontario joined this linked cap-and-trade system.
Case Study #3: United Kingdom
The United Kingdom uses a hybrid carbon-pricing system, with elements of both cap-and-trade and a carbon tax.
Since 2005, the UK has participated in the European Union’s cap-and-trade system, which has a current permit price of less than £10 per tonne (around $18 Canadian). Since 2001, the UK has also had a domestic “Climate Change Levy,” which is a tax on electricity, gasoline, and other fuels supplied to firms. In 2013, the UK started increasing its domestic carbon tax to support the EU’s cap-and-trade system. The UK’s carbon tax differs from BC’s in a few key ways. For example, different sectors in the UK pay different levels of carbon taxes, whereas BC’s carbon tax is economy-wide.
The UK’s domestic carbon tax is now £18 per tonne (around $33 Canadian), and creates incentives additional to those created by the EU’s cap-and-trade system. In other words, domestic industries pay both carbon prices. For example, if the EU permit price were £8 per tonne, UK industries would pay a total carbon price of £26 per tonne (around $47 Canadian). If the EU permit price were to fall to zero, UK industries would still pay £18 per tonne for their GHG emissions.
Since 2000, the UK has seen a sharp decline in its total GHG emissions, and the drop has become steeper over the last few years.
As Figure 1 illustrates, the UK’s emissions have fallen faster than those in the rest of the EU, which has a cap-and-trade system but (for most countries) no additional carbon tax.
Why does carbon pricing work?
Why do higher carbon prices lead to lower GHG emissions? The underlying logic is based on an essential economic truth: prices influence behaviour.
Prices affect choices throughout the economy
First, think about prices of other goods and services. If the price of cauliflower increases, many people choose broccoli instead. If the price of parking increases, many people choose instead to take the bus or subway to work. If the price of winter beach vacations increases, many people choose instead to have local holidays. An increase in cigarette taxes helped to reduce the number of smokers. The same kind of response holds for choices all through the economy.
Here’s a specific example from history: in the 1970s, the world price of oil spiked significantly on two occasions, both of which led to sharp increases in gasoline prices in Canada. In response, drivers’ choices changed. In the short term, people drove less. In the medium term, fuel-efficient vehicles became more popular, so people might have driven the same amount, but they used less gasoline while doing so. The reason was simple: buying a more fuel-efficient car meant saving money. People (and businesses) like to save money when they can and when they have options to do so. Prices influenced behaviour.
Carbon pricing affects many different choices. It increases the costs of any activity (driving, flying, heating, etc.) based on how much carbon dioxide it produces. But that doesn’t mean that anyone and everyone simply pay a higher cost. After all, individuals and businesses have choices. Those choices give them ways to avoid paying the carbon price. And in fact, that’s exactly the point.
An example: carbon prices affect driving choices
To illustrate why carbon pricing works, let’s consider our choices around driving and how carbon pricing can affect them. The carbon price will make gasoline a little more expensive. How might your driving behaviour change as a result?
Most drivers have options in how they respond. Some seek opportunities to carpool. Others take the bus or train to work instead of driving. Others take more dramatic action like buying a smaller car—some even get rid of their car altogether (thus saving money on fuel plus many other car-related expenses). Others move closer to work. Some people might not change their behaviour at all, choosing instead simply to pay the carbon price on their unchanged gasoline usage.
Evidence shows that these kinds of decisions actually happen. Two UBC economists found that BC’s carbon tax reduced demand for fuel by 7%, and that a little less than half of those reductions were from changes in driving habits. Similarly, evidence from Denmark finds that a 10% increase in the price of fuel causes the average driver to reduce driving by 3%. In other words: prices influence behaviour.
Why do drivers make these choices? Because of the relative costs of the various options available. If making a different choice is easy (perhaps because a driver lives close to public transit) then it has low costs (for example, in terms of the time required).
By letting drivers choose how to respond (or not), a carbon-pricing policy lets individuals—rather than governments—identify the most preferred approaches to reducing GHG emissions.
Carbon prices can also affect vehicle choices
Changes in driving behaviour probably aren’t the only — or even the most important — way drivers respond to a higher carbon price. Over time, the policy will also affect the vehicles they purchase.
Let’s consider four Canadians in very different circumstances who share the need to buy a new car:
Different vehicles have different fuel economies. This means they produce different amounts of GHG emissions, so they also have different carbon costs under a carbon price.
Our four individuals have choices when it comes to buying a new vehicle. The carbon price can affect which vehicle they choose and thus the GHG emissions they ultimately create while driving that vehicle.
To unpack these vehicle choices, let’s consider the four options for a new vehicle in Table 1. We can see that different vehicles have their own advantages and disadvantages, both financial and non-financial (precise numbers will vary; think of these rankings as illustrative).
Which vehicles do our four drivers prefer? Let’s think about that question in three different contexts.
Begin in the situation without carbon pricing, in which case producing GHG emissions is costless to the individual. In this case:
Now consider the choices under a carbon price that rises over time. Emitters will therefore pay for the carbon emissions they produce. In this case:
In our example, the carbon price affects vehicle choices of two of the four drivers. It causes them to choose more fuel-efficient vehicles to save money on gasoline. It also therefore reduces GHG emissions, relative to the scenario without the carbon price.
While our example here is illustrative, it’s not far from reality. Those same UBC economists, for example, found that on average, the mix of vehicles driven in BC would have been 4% less fuel-efficient had BC not implemented its carbon tax. The carbon price will not affect every vehicle purchase, but it will affect some. Over time those choices that reduce emissions add up. In other words: carbon pricing works because prices influence behaviour.
The great advantage of a carbon-pricing policy is the flexibility it provides. It lets individual Canadians or businesses make their own choices about how to respond — or not — to the price, based on the costs of doing so. That flexibility keeps the costs of those emissions reductions low.
In contrast, consider a third policy scenario. Governments sometimes try to reduce GHG emissions by providing cash rebates for consumers’ purchases of low-emission, electric vehicles. Let’s see our four drivers’ vehicle choices in this case:
We compare the outcomes across the three policy scenarios in Table 2. The EV rebate does lead to some emissions reductions because it causes Alex to buy the Bolt. But because it promotes a specific technology, the rebate has narrower impacts than the carbon price: Derek has no incentive to buy the Outback instead of the Civic, so the EV rebate does not affect his behaviour at all.
Furthermore, the EV rebate has costs that the carbon price doesn’t. Charlotte, for example, gets the rebate even though she would have purchased the Bolt anyway. Those taxpayer dollars are effectively wasted. The result? The rebate reduces GHG emissions at a higher cost than putting a price on carbon.
Recent analysis from the Ecofiscal Commission found that EV rebates in Quebec reduce GHG emissions at a cost around $400 per tonne, while BC’s carbon tax is currently reducing emissions at less than $35 per tonne.
Carbon prices drive innovation
The story of why carbon pricing works still isn’t done. Carbon pricing will have another lasting effect: it will create long-term incentives for the innovation of low-emissions technologies.
A good carbon-pricing policy doesn’t just price emissions in the present and drive emissions reductions today, it also creates expectations for higher carbon prices in the future. In response, innovative engineers and entrepreneurs have strong and rising incentives to develop technologies that reduce GHG emissions even further.
As new technologies emerge, additional options for reducing emissions become available. As a result, the costs of reducing emissions gets lower and lower over time. As an additional benefit, those innovators might be able to sell their products and ideas internationally, helping to reduce emissions elsewhere.
In the context of our vehicle example, as the costs of batteries decline, so too will the costs of electric vehicles. That means a steadily rising carbon price will shift more vehicle choices. In the future, carbon pricing is likely to cause Alex and Derek to choose electric vehicles rather than gas-powered or hybrid options. Similarly, electric trucks and Sport Utility Vehicles will become available, and at more affordable prices, which means a carbon price might also affect Barbara’s choices.
WATCH: Carbon pricing produces two types of economic incentives.
Carbon prices affect choices all across the economy
To be clear, our vehicle example is just a parable. It considers four hypothetical individuals in the context of a single choice. But the lessons from this simple example have general implications for carbon pricing.
First, the choice of vehicle is only one of thousands of choices that businesses and individuals will make about their behaviour, purchases, and investments. Just as a carbon price will change the trade-offs around vehicles, it will affect choices around home insulation, fuel use in industrial processes, and investments in pension plans.
Some methods of reducing GHG emissions will help businesses or households save money by allowing them to avoid paying the carbon price. Just as importantly, some decisions won’t be affected by the price. If an action to reduce emissions is very expensive, the carbon price will not require businesses or individuals to take that action. And that’s OK:
The idea is not to force anyone to take specific actions (like some regulations might do) but rather to let prices change incentives and let incentives affect choices. Households and businesses always face choices.
Over time, we need deeper emissions reductions. That’s why a rising carbon price is so important. As the carbon price increases, it will affect more decisions, resulting in more emissions reductions. But even a carbon price of $100 per tonne won’t force actions that cost $200 or even thousands of dollars per tonne. A predictable and gradually rising path for the carbon price will let individuals and businesses plan for the future, again keeping costs down.
Second, millions of other Canadian consumers and businesses will also face that same choice. Every one of them will have their own context and preferences. Some will have more opportunities to reduce GHG emissions inexpensively. Others might have different opportunities, or fewer opportunities. And that’s exactly the point: those that have low-cost alternatives will respond to a carbon price in the way that makes most sense for them. As a whole, this means we can realize the lowest-cost ways to reduce GHG emissions throughout the economy, without forcing anyone to take the high-cost actions.
When designed well, carbon pricing applies to all emissions in the economy and all emitters — individuals as well as businesses. This broad coverage creates a common incentive for everyone to reduce emissions in low-cost ways.
In short, we can extrapolate our example across all GHG emissions in Canada. Carbon prices affect choices. That’s why a price on carbon can efficiently drive emissions reductions, and why it already has done so in British Columbia, California, the UK, and elsewhere, as we saw in the Where section.
When does carbon pricing work?
The impacts of carbon pricing aren’t instantaneous, and we shouldn’t expect immediate results. But nobody should conclude that carbon pricing doesn’t work just because things don’t change dramatically in the short term. Monitoring the GHG impact of carbon pricing is like watching paint dry.
Our story of driving and vehicles illustrates why carbon pricing works. But it also illustrates when. Figure 3 sketches a timeline for when businesses and individuals respond to carbon pricing.
The gradual impact of a steadily rising carbon price helps to keep adjustment costs low. Replacing old equipment before it is necessary can be expensive. Carbon pricing gives businesses and individuals choices as to when to make these investments. The gradual transition gives everyone time to respond to the policy and plan their investments accordingly.
All these gradual changes add up across the economy and over time
Achieving deep GHG reductions at lowest cost is a long-run objective. Carbon-pricing policies in Canada are still young, with modest impacts so far. But gradual impacts from actions taken now accumulate into enormous impacts over time. And as carbon prices steadily increase, emissions levels will decrease, and cumulative emissions reductions will continue to grow. Our analysis from a previous report, shown in Figure 4, shows how a rising carbon price can drive large GHG reductions over time. Notice that, in this example, all the revenues raised by the carbon tax are used to finance cuts in other taxes—which makes the carbon tax revenue neutral.
WATCH: Carbon pricing works because people try to avoid it.
Who supports carbon pricing?
Support for carbon pricing comes from a remarkable range of perspectives.
Carbon pricing is spreading across the world
Many jurisdictions are implementing various kinds of carbon-pricing policies. Carbon pricing has spread to every continent, as Figure 5 illustrates. Countries, provinces, and states are choosing the type of carbon pricing that suits their unique circumstances—and learning and improving as they go. China is one of the latest countries to get on board. It launched its first cap-and-trade system in late 2017.
Carbon pricing has some unexpected advocates
Support for carbon pricing is broader than you might expect. Here is a sample of the kinds of people that have advocated carbon pricing as the best way to reduce GHG emissions and maintain a strong economy at the same time.
Carbon pricing has support from Canadians
What about support among Canadians? Earlier this year, we commissioned polling on Canadians’ attitudes toward carbon pricing. The results are instructive.
Despite some occasionally heated rhetoric, most Canadians support carbon pricing.
Almost four out of five of those surveyed thought that carbon pricing was at least an “acceptable” idea, and 46% thought it was a good or very good idea. As Figure 6 illustrates, results vary somewhat by region. Opposition is strongest in Alberta, but 65% of Albertans surveyed still thought carbon pricing was at least an acceptable idea.
In addition, Canadian attitudes toward carbon pricing are slowly shifting. Compared to 2015, more Canadians think carbon pricing is a good or very good idea, and more people support it as a way to reduce emissions.
Not everyone who learns about carbon pricing will end up supporting it. And perhaps those who care about the environment are more likely to expend the effort to learn about carbon prices. At the very least, these results suggest that it might be a good idea for Canadians to learn a little more about carbon pricing and how it works.
WATCH: Canadians want to be part of the global solution.
How do policies put a price on carbon?
So how does carbon pricing work? How do policies put a price on carbon? Carbon pricing looks very different in the three jurisdictions we discussed in the Where section, but they’re all based on the same idea. There are two basic approaches: carbon taxes and cap-and-trade systems. Variations of these two policies (and even hybrids) exist, but our focus here is on the basics of the policies, not their many details. We will look at carbon taxes and cap-and-trade systems in their simplest forms.
Carbon taxes directly set a price on carbon
A carbon tax sets the price on carbon directly. It applies to specific fuels based on how many GHGs are emitted when they are burned. Emitters pay a fixed fee to the government for every tonne of GHG emissions.
With this design, more carbon-intensive fuels have a higher carbon tax. In British Columbia, for example, the tax is currently set at $35 per tonne of GHGs. This translates to a little under 8 cents per litre of gasoline, a little over 9 cents per litre of diesel, and $1.77 per GJ (gigajoules) of natural gas. (One litre of diesel produces slightly more GHGs than one litre of gasoline, which explains why the tax per litre is slightly higher for diesel, but the tax per tonne of GHGs is identical for the two fuels.)
Businesses and individuals can choose to change their behaviour to reduce their GHG emissions, thus reducing the amount of carbon tax they pay. In extreme cases they can avoid paying the tax entirely if they can get to zero emissions. Leaving these decisions to businesses and individuals is exactly what makes carbon pricing work.
The following video illustrates how it works:
WATCH: A carbon price incentivizes households and businesses to find ways to reduce their emissions.
Cap-and-trade systems create a market that establishes a price on carbon
Cap-and-trade systems also create a carbon price but in an indirect way.
A government begins by establishing a maximum allowable level of GHG emissions in its jurisdiction; this is the cap on emissions. It then allocates emissions permits to industrial facilities, fuel distributors, and other large emitters, either by selling them or providing them for free. These businesses can emit GHGs only up to their total number of permits. The difference between the total amount of current emissions (without the policy) and the emissions “cap” determines the size of the reduction in GHG emissions.
Where is the carbon price in this picture? The key point is that businesses are allowed to buy and sell emission permits among themselves; this is the trade part of cap-and-trade.
Firms that need more permits (so that they don’t have to reduce their emissions as much) will demand them and purchase them from the market. Other firms that don’t need all their permits (because they plan to cut their emissions) will supply and sell them to the market. This supply and demand for permits determines the market price of carbon.
Trading in this market determines who will reduce emissions (and sell permits) and who will increase emissions (and buy permits).
The net effect of this pattern of emissions and trading is that GHG emissions get reduced by the required amount and at the lowest possible cost. Why? Because the firms that are able to reduce emissions at the lowest cost are the ones that will realize the most reductions; the firms that are able to reduce emissions only at a higher cost cut their emissions by less or not at all.
All emitters in a cap-and-trade system have a profit-driven incentive to reduce their emissions, but they respond differently because of their different costs and technologies.
The following video illustrates how it works:
WATCH: Cap-and-trade limits emissions while motivating companies with low-cost emissions to take more action, resulting with lower reduction costs to the economy.
These ideas bring us back to the purpose of this essay: our goal is to explain where and why carbon pricing has worked, and how. Before we get to our conclusions and recommendations, we’ll address a few questions that may have popped up along the way.
Other FAQs about carbon pricing
Our focus has been the “who, what, when, where, why, and how” of carbon pricing, which reduces GHG emissions while supporting a strong economy. But other more detailed questions about carbon pricing also frequently arise. We address these questions (briefly) here, with links to deeper analysis.
WATCH: The economic benefits we get from overall carbon pricing policy are influenced by how governments use the revenues.
Conclusions
Well-designed policies that put a price on carbon can reduce GHG emissions and can do so in a way that doesn’t undermine our economic prosperity.
Carbon pricing works. We have shown where carbon pricing has worked—in terms of both environmental and economic outcomes—in provinces, states, and countries that have implemented carbon-pricing policies. Experience in British Columbia, California and the United Kingdom provide real-world evidence of successful carbon pricing.
We have shown why carbon pricing works—using a simple example of how a carbon price might affect the vehicles we purchase, and why.
Carbon pricing is all about incentives and flexibility. It reduces costs by preserving choice for individuals and businesses.
We have shown when carbon pricing works by considering impacts in the short, medium, and long terms.
Carbon pricing works gradually and incrementally over time. But over the long term, these effects accumulate enormously.
We have shown who accepts that carbon pricing works by looking at the breadth of jurisdictions across the globe moving forward with policies, as well as the support from a broad cross-section of individual policy voices.
Finally, we have shown how policies put a price on carbon by explaining cap-and-trade systems and carbon taxes. Both systems can work and are actually more similar than they are different.
Carbon pricing is about the "rules of the market," not specific outcomes
Our findings might be a little unexpected, and perhaps contrary to some of the many carbon-pricing myths floating around. The point of carbon pricing isn’t to punish polluters. It is not to generate revenue (though it does do that). And it’s definitely not about promoting specific "green" technologies.
Instead, carbon pricing is about making the "rules of the market" work better, and letting individual producers and consumers make their own choices within that context.
Market prices should tell the truth about what carbon really costs us. Carbon pricing does that. And then it lets individuals and businesses respond in ways that work for them. The overall result is that we get lower GHG emissions without harming the overall performance of the economy.
Recommendations
Canada has made enormous progress on carbon pricing over the last several years, but there is more to be done. We close off this essay with three recommendations.
Recommendation #1: Canadian provinces should rely on increasingly stringent carbon pricing policies to reduce GHG emissions
Carbon pricing already covers the majority of GHG emissions in Canada. Governments should continue to make carbon pricing the central plank of their climate policy, and they should add well-designed non-pricing policies only when carbon pricing alone can’t do the job. This will ensure that Canada reduces GHG emissions at the lowest possible economic cost.
And the stringency of carbon pricing policies across Canada should continue to increase gradually over time. Canadian provinces can achieve the deeper emissions reductions required by steadily increasing the rates of carbon taxes or steadily reducing the number of permits in cap-and-trade systems. Higher carbon prices and lower caps will lead to deeper emissions reductions. The expectation of rising carbon prices will strengthen incentives for emitters to innovate and invest in low-carbon technologies. Steady, predictable increases in stringency will ensure that individuals and businesses have time to adjust and plan their long-term investments accordingly.
Recommendation #2: Policy makers and analysts should work to better communicate the realities of carbon pricing
We’ve come a long way in Canada. We have real, working examples of both carbon taxes and cap-and-trade systems. But pervasive myths about carbon pricing still cause too much of the debate to be based on poor information.
We appreciate that carbon pricing isn’t always simple, especially when it comes to the important details of policy design. It is incumbent on all of us engaged in climate policy to communicate beyond a narrow group of technical policy experts. Carbon pricing affects all Canadians, so we need to help all Canadians understand the basics. That’s why we wrote this essay — so please pass it on.
We can’t afford to base important policy decisions on myths and misunderstandings; critics of carbon pricing ought to base their arguments on evidence. There is plenty of room to debate the different methods of carbon pricing, various approaches to revenue recycling, how fast the carbon price should rise, or what other climate policies may be necessary. But arguing that prices don’t affect decisions is arguing against a large body of economic theory, against an enormous amount of empirical evidence, and most importantly, against most people’s own experiences.
Having a better public conversation about carbon pricing can help us move forward.
Recommendation #3: Governments should carefully evaluate their carbon-pricing policies over time, especially in the medium term.
Nothing is more convincing than hard data. To show that carbon pricing works, governments should undertake careful, detailed analysis of how carbon pricing has performed in their jurisdictions. That analysis should isolate the effects of carbon pricing from other factors. It should explicitly show the impacts of the policy on GHG emissions and the economy by estimating what environmental and economic outcomes would have been in the absence of the carbon price. This robust data and analysis should be clearly communicated to the public.
And if, over time, evidence accumulates that existing carbon-pricing policies haven’t worked as theory—and experience—suggests they will, governments should be prepared to revisit or redesign these policies as necessary.
Carbon pricing will be most effective over time. Our transition to a low-carbon economy will not occur overnight, but instead gradually, as firms and individuals develop and adopt new technologies. Evaluation and adjustment over time are important, but must also be tempered by patience.